The following is the established format for referencing this article:
Schill, C., T. Lindahl, and A.-S. Crépin. 2015. Collective action and the risk of ecosystem regime shifts: insights from a laboratory experiment. Ecology and Society 20(1): 48.ABSTRACT
Ecosystems can undergo regime shifts that potentially lead to a substantial decrease in the availability of provisioning ecosystem services. Recent research suggests that the frequency and intensity of regime shifts increase with growing anthropogenic pressure, so understanding the underlying social-ecological dynamics is crucial, particularly in contexts where livelihoods depend heavily on local ecosystem services. In such settings, ecosystem services are often derived from common-pool resources. The limited capacity to predict regime shifts is a major challenge for common-pool resource management, as well as for systematic empirical analysis of individual and group behavior, because of the need for extensive preshift and postshift data. Unsurprisingly, current knowledge is mostly based on theoretical models. We examine behavioral group responses to a latent endogenously driven regime shift in a laboratory experiment. If the group exploited the common-pool resource beyond a certain threshold level, its renewal rate dropped drastically. To determine how the risk of such a latent shift affects resource management and collective action, we compared four experimental treatments in which groups were faced with a latent shift with different probability levels (0.1, 0.5, 0.9, 1.0). Our results suggest that different probability levels do not make people more or less likely to exploit the resource beyond its critical potential threshold. However, when the likelihood of the latent shift is certain or high, people appear more prone to agree initially on a common exploitation strategy, which in turn is a predictor for averting the latent shift. Moreover, risk appears to have a positive effect on collective action, but the magnitude of this effect is influenced by how risk and probabilities are communicated and perceived.INTRODUCTION
There is growing evidence that ecosystems at different scales can experience so-called regime shifts: large, abrupt, and potentially persistent changes in system structure and dynamics (Folke et al. 2004, Biggs et al. 2012). These shifts can have major impacts on bundles of produced ecosystem services crucial for human well-being (Millennium Ecosystem Assessment 2005, Stern 2007, Crépin et al. 2012). Moreover, recent research suggests that the frequency and intensity of ecosystem regime shifts will increase as climate change becomes more drastic and other sources of anthropogenic forces become more acute (Steffen et al. 2004, Millennium Ecosystem Assessment 2005, Rockström et al. 2009). There is growing understanding about drivers of regime shifts, their impacts on ecosystems, and how those impacts link to human well-being (see, e.g., Scheffer et al. 2001, Gordon et al. 2008, Rocha et al. 2015, and the Regime Shifts database, http://www.regimeshifts.org, for an overview of case studies). However, empirical research on how people deal with the possibility that their actions may induce ecosystem regime shifts, affecting the flow of ecosystem services, has to our knowledge gained only little attention in the scientific literature. We examine the role of uncertainty associated with human-induced ecosystem regime shifts with a negative influence on local ecosystem service availability. We addressed the following research question: How does the risk of a latent endogenously driven undesirable ecosystem regime shift influence user group exploitation strategies (resource management) and collective action?
Regime shifts occur when the values of key ecosystem variables cross critical thresholds, either because of external pressures or endogenous processes as in this study. The critical threshold value leading from one regime to another often differs from that leading back to the initial regime. This is called hysteresis and results from the presence of internal feedback loops that maintain the new regime, making the shift difficult to reverse (Biggs et al. 2012). We conceptualize the flow of services from the local ecosystem to the resource users and the interventions of the resource users in the ecosystem, including resource use and management, as a coupled social-ecological system (Berkes and Folke 1998). Recognizing and studying these dynamic social-ecological linkages are particularly relevant in contexts in which livelihoods depend heavily on resource flow from local ecosystems and substitution opportunities are rare. In such contexts, regime shifts can threaten livelihoods (Turner et al. 2003). Provisioning ecosystem services, e.g., fish or irrigation water, are often derived from so-called common-pool resources (CPRs; Cárdenas 2009). CPRs are characterized by nonexcludability, and the resource units are subtractable; typical examples include fisheries or irrigation systems (Ostrom 1990). Therefore, we focused on a CPR management situation in which avoiding regime shifts depends on successful local collective action.
The ecosystem regime shifts considered in this study are latent and endogenously driven in the sense that only group action, i.e., overexploitation, could trigger them; and they are undesirable because of their negative influence on the availability of a commonly used and managed provisioning ecosystem service. There are many uncertainties associated with the dynamics of ecosystems, because they are complex and adaptive (Levin 1998). In general, the predictability of ecosystem dynamics is limited (Hastings and Wysham 2010). Because of hysteresis, the impact of factors influencing an ecosystem response may differ significantly at two different points in time, depending on previous events (Holling 1987, Wilson 2002). Assessing the existence of thresholds and anticipating regime shifts are often associated with large uncertainties (Scheffer et al. 2001). Techniques to detect regime shifts in time have recently been developed (e.g., Biggs et al. 2009, Brock and Carpenter 2012, Lade and Gross 2012, Scheffer et al. 2012), but it is unclear whether such early warning signals appear early enough to implement management actions and avoid regime shifts (Biggs et al. 2009). The ecological uncertainty can translate into risks for resource users dependent on the ecosystem. To our knowledge, current understanding of the mechanisms underlying CPR management under risk of ecosystem regime shifts stems mostly from theoretical models. Thus, this empirical study fills an important research gap.
We continued the empirical work started by Lindahl et al. (2012, 2014) on collective action in the face of latent endogenously driven ecosystem regime shifts by introducing uncertainty or more specifically, risk, because this is a typical feature of regime shifts. Lindahl et al. (2012, 2014) investigated experimentally how user groups in a commons dilemma respond to latent endogenously driven ecosystem regime shifts by comparing two experimental treatments, one involving a simple resource dynamic without a threshold, i.e., no threshold treatment, and the other resource dynamics with an abrupt and drastic drop in resource renewal rate beyond a critical threshold in the resource stock, i.e., threshold treatment. They found that groups facing a latent regime shift manage the CPR more efficiently than groups facing simple resource dynamics. The threat of reaching a critical threshold through their own actions appears to trigger more effective communication, i.e., making agreements, which leads to stronger commitment for cooperation, more knowledge sharing within the group, and consequently more efficient resource management.
That empirical work complements recent theoretical work in economics on CPR management in the face of ecosystem regime shifts. Mäler et al. (2003) demonstrated that the existence of latent regime shifts in lakes can complicate lake management and that noncooperation can trigger undesirable regime shifts. Crépin and Lindahl (2009) found examples where latent regime shifts could cause overexploitation or underexploitation of common grasslands. These results were derived from theoretical mathematical models and thus were based on rationality assumptions. For example, users either cooperate or they do not. When users cooperate, it is further assumed that the resource is managed optimally (so-called group rationality). When they do not cooperate, each user makes a management plan, including all possible game states, and sticks to that plan, i.e., follows an open-loop Nash strategy. Theoretical studies focusing on optimal management also show that ecosystem regime shifts result in considerable management challenges (e.g., Brock and Starrett 2003, Crépin 2003, 2007). Optimal regulations may depend on past actions, and mistakes can be difficult to correct (Levin et al. 2013). However, all these contributions are based on assumptions of full knowledge of ecosystem dynamics without uncertainty.
Polasky et al. (2011) studied the impact of latent endogenously driven regime shifts on optimal management and suggested that in the presence of such shifts, and under certain conditions, an optimal management strategy would be precautionary action and reduced harvesting pressure to reduce shift probability. In commons dilemmas, however, resource users make individual management decisions and do not act as a single decision-making unit. Some experimental studies in social psychology have investigated how resource users in commons dilemmas react to uncertainty regarding resource stock size and/or regeneration rate, so-called environmental uncertainty (Messick et al. 1988). Studies focusing on resource stock size uncertainty show that experiment participants, i.e., subjects, request significantly more from the resource pool with increasing uncertainty about its size (Budescu et al. 1990, Rapoport et al. 1992, Gustafsson et al. 1999). Hine and Gifford (1996) replicated these results in a framed experiment with a group of subjects who managed a fishery over several seasons, considering also regeneration rate uncertainty. The dynamic nature of that experiment, i.e., past decisions influenced current and future conditions (path dependency), contrasts with the repeated single-trial games used by Budescu et al. and shows that the effects of environmental uncertainty can be extended to dynamic and more realistic games (Hine and Gifford 1996).
The bulk of experimental work on commons dilemmas originates from the work of Ostrom (1990) on the governance of CPRs; see Ostrom et al. (1994) on the so-called CPR baseline game. These CPR experiments are mostly performed by experimental economists and interdisciplinary researchers, and usually focus on institutional aspects (Sturm and Weimann 2006) of the dilemma, thereby ignoring potentially relevant ecosystem characteristics. A notable exception is the work of Walker and Gardner (1992), who early went beyond a static ecological environment. They extended the CPR baseline game by including path dependence, so that past choices influenced the probability of CPR destruction in the following round, to investigate how this affects resource management efficiency. They found that resource destruction prevailed, in most cases quite rapidly.
Ecological complexities have only recently been taken into account in this strand of work (Cárdenas 2009, Poteete et al. 2010) to better approximate key linkages of complex social-ecological systems (Ostrom 2009, Anderies et al. 2011). For example, Janssen et al. (2010) and Janssen (2010) introduced spatial and temporal dynamics, whereas Cardenas et al. (2013) introduced endogenously driven resource dynamics. Osés-Eraso et al. (2008) compared exogenous, i.e., environmental, and endogenous, i.e., human-induced, resource scarcity; Moreno-Sánchez and Maldonado (2010) examined contrasting resource states, i.e., abundant versus scarce; and Kimbrough and Vostroknutov (2013) determined the effects of differing resource replenishment rates. The experimental design developed by Cardenas et al. (2013) and used by Castillo et al. (2011) and Prediger et al. (2011) in different field contexts also includes spatial variability, in that subjects made two binary decisions, e.g., one about where to harvest and the other about how much to harvest. Locations with excessive harvest pressure experienced temporary resource degradation (no depletion), which is costly to reverse. Although not explicitly stated by the authors, this could be interpreted as a regime shift. Overall, these studies demonstrate unsuccessful management because the resource in both locations degraded and did not recover. In some cases, however, Prediger et al. found that groups managed the resource more carefully to avoid degradation, an effect they attributed to cultural and ecological factors the subjects face in reality. It is important to note that only three of the above-mentioned studies (Janssen 2010, Janssen et al. 2010, Moreno-Sánchez and Maldonado 2010) permitted communication in some treatments between subjects, and only the studies by Janssen and colleagues involved stochastic resource dynamics. To our knowledge, the present study is the first to focus on the factors that enable CPR users to maintain desirable ecological conditions under the risk of latent endogenously driven ecosystem regime shifts in a setting in which communication is allowed.
To test our research question, we used a framed laboratory CPR experiment that extends the design developed by Lindahl et al. (2012). We introduced three risk treatments and compared those with the threshold treatment of Lindahl et al. This allowed us to explore group behavior in the face of a latent endogenously driven regime shift with four different probability levels: 0.1, 0.5, and 0.9 (risk treatments) and 1.0 (threshold treatment).
EXPERIMENTAL SETTING
Experimental design
Our laboratory experiment consisted of a CPR request game (see Budescu et al. 1992). Apart from its dynamic nature and the inclusion of complex ecological dynamics, i.e., threshold and hysteresis effect in resource dynamics, this game features some distinct characteristics that distinguish it from other CPR games: The framing is not neutral in that the task and information given to subjects are not abstract but rather resemble field context; i.e., the subjects are asked to harvest units of a renewable resource instead of collecting tokens (see Harrison and List 2004 for a taxonomy of experiments). Furthermore, and perhaps the most distinctive characteristic, subjects are allowed to communicate face-to-face from the start and at any time, rather than being restricted to a communication stage after the decision round. Discussions are not restricted in terms of time or content. Subjects can disclose and/or discuss their individual harvest rates and agree on a common exploitation strategy. Moreover, to approximate an infinite time horizon, the subjects do not know the exact number of rounds to be played, only that the experiment session lasts a maximum of two hours. Ostrom et al. (1994) used a similar approach. These choices stem from our intention to mimic field conditions as closely as possible. Because we intend to bring this experimental design to the field, we used pencil and paper instead of a computer-based experiment in this application (Janssen et al. 2014). For a more detailed description of the design, see Lindahl et al. (2012).
In all four experimental treatments (see Table 1 for overview), a group of subjects managed a renewable CPR. The only aspect that differed between treatments was the probability level (0.1, 0.5, 0.9, 1.0) with which the groups faced a threshold in the resource dynamics of the CPR. Following Schill (2012), we introduced the risk of a threshold by showing the subjects in the risk treatments the resource dynamics (using figures and tables; Appendix 1) of two different scenarios (A and B; Fig. 1a, b) and informed them that one of those scenarios was being played with a given probability. Subjects were also told that the scenario was selected ex ante by flipping a coin (0.5 probability treatment) or making a random draw (0.1 and 0.9 probability treatments). Subjects in the threshold treatment (1.0 probability) were presented only with the resource dynamics of scenario B.
Figure 1a shows the resource dynamics of scenario A, which is a discrete version of the logistic growth function. This scenario entails only smooth changes in the regeneration rate, i.e., no threshold. Scenario B includes a threshold in the resource dynamics (Fig. 1b). If the stock size decreases from one round to the other, e.g., from 20 to 19 units, the regeneration rate decreases from 7 to 1. Because of a hysteresis effect, which we incorporated because it often occurs in regime shift dynamics, this decrease is not only drastic, but also persistent. To regain a regeneration rate of 7 units, the resource stock needs to be rebuilt to 25 units or more, i.e., the group cannot harvest anything for 5 rounds (compare the black and grey bars in Fig. 1b).
In all treatments, groups started with the maximum possible resource stock size of 50 units. Over a number of rounds, they extracted resource stock units worth SEK 5 (≈ EUR 0.50/USD 0.70) each.
Experimental procedure
The experiment was conducted at the Swedish Royal Academy of Sciences, Stockholm, Sweden, between May 2010 and December 2013 and involved 307 subjects recruited from the Stockholm University campus. Each subject was randomly assigned to a group of four subjects, but when only three subjects showed up, we ran the experiment anyway and tested the effect of group size. Each subject participated only once and in only one of the four treatments. They received a show-up fee of SEK 150 (≈ EUR 16/USD 22) in cash, paid privately at the end of the experiment together with the individual earnings, which varied between SEK 55 and SEK 248 with a mean of SEK 176 (≈ EUR 19/USD 26). See Table 2 for average earnings per treatment and information on their significance for students in Sweden. We gathered 20 groups (73 subjects) for the threshold treatment, 21 groups (77 subjects) for the high-risk treatment, 23 groups (87 subjects) for the medium-risk treatment, and 20 groups (70 subjects) for the low-risk treatment (see Table 1). See Table 2 for general characteristics of the subject pool.
On arrival, the subjects were seated around a table, signed a consent form, were informed about what would happen in the following maximum two hours, and were given the instructions to read (see Appendix 1). Afterwards, the experimenter went through an example with the group and remaining questions were clarified.
The subjects were instructed that they each represented a fictive resource user and that they, together with other group members, had common access to a renewable resource stock. They were told that the experiment would last several rounds and that in each round they were to make an individual, private decision on how many units they would like to harvest and record that on a form (see Appendix 1). Individual decisions were anonymous in that subjects were not allowed to show each other what they had written down on the form, but because there were no restrictions with respect to communication, they could orally disclose their individual harvest rates.
After each round, the experimenter calculated the total group harvest and the new stock size to be disclosed to the group. The subjects knew that as long as there were units to harvest, the experiment would continue for a number of rounds. In that case, the experimenter stopped the group after 14 rounds. In case of resource stock depletion, which happened if the group’s total harvest exceeded the available resource stock size, the game ended and the payment to each subject in that round was based on each subject’s harvest share of the group’s total harvest in that same round (see equation in Instructions; Appendix 1).
After the experiment, the subjects filled out a questionnaire (see Appendix 2). Apart from the usual demographic questions (age, gender, nationality), they were asked whether they knew someone in the group from before. They were also asked to indicate, on a five-point Likert scale (Likert 1932), to what extent they disagreed/agreed with statements about their understanding of resource dynamics and about various factors known from the literature to be relevant for cooperation in commons dilemmas. The Likert scale ranged from one (strong disagreement) to five (strong agreement). Table A3.1 in Appendix 3 lists the questionnaire variables selected. The experimenters also took notes during the course of the experiment, for example, on the exploitation strategies groups decided on or reasons for depletion.
We also ran a risk game to explore the risk preferences of our subjects. We performed 4 treatments and gathered 253 observations (see Appendix 4).
Formulating hypotheses
The outcome of this dynamic CPR game for one group was one of several alternatives. For example, the group could cooperate and maximize its joint returns, which is the optimal and most efficient outcome. Here we followed Lindahl et al. (2014) and measured efficiency as the share of actual joint earnings over the maximum possible. This optimal and efficient outcome occurred if the group harvested 25 resource stock units in the first round, and thereafter 9 units per round, corresponding to the maximum sustainable yield, as long as each group member believed that the game would continue for 1 more round with sufficiently high probability. Note that this was true for all treatments. If the stock fell below 25 units for some reason, the optimal strategy for eventually obtaining large harvests again was to let the resource recover until it reached 34 units and then to harvest 9 units in subsequent rounds (see Table A5.1 in Appendix 5 for optimal claims per stock size).
Another outcome was the other extreme, whereby the group depleted the resource entirely at some point. In between these two extremes were potential outcomes in which the group overexploited the resource and perhaps even crossed the potential threshold. In other possible outcomes, total exploitation could be less than the optimal exploitation level. Thus, we defined overexploitation, or tragedies, as exploitation above the optimal, and vice versa for underexploitation. If the group overexploited the resource to the point at which they crossed the potential threshold, the tragedy was more severe because the drop in the regeneration rate was significant and persistent. We called these two types of overexploitation modest overexploitation (stock size 20-24) and severe overexploitation (after crossing the potential threshold). Note the adjective “potential” added to the latter definition, an important distinction because we were interested in whether groups would risk crossing the potential threshold while not knowing which scenario they were actually playing. In all but the threshold treatment, the actual conditions of the experiment were revealed to the subjects on crossing the potential threshold, so that treatment uncertainty was resolved. Our main variable of interest was whether or not groups crossed the potential threshold.
Following Lindahl et al. (2014), we formulated hypotheses, based on repeated game theory methods, to guide the analysis of the results. See Appendix 6 for the underlying intuition and proofs of hypotheses.
Hypothesis 1
Hypothesis 1 was that the higher the probability of a threshold, the fewer cases of severe overexploitation. In other words, we expected fewer groups to cross the potential threshold.
If groups fully used the communication opportunity and cooperate, then it was rational for the group to follow the optimal group strategy and not cross the potential threshold, regardless of treatment. It can be debated, however, whether cooperative groups really display this type of group rationality. We defined a cooperative group as one able to reach agreement with respect to its exploitation strategy for the entire experiment and with the agreements followed by all group members, i.e., with no cheating. This implies that only groups that communicate can be classified as cooperative groups. However, it does not include whether a cooperative group actually manages the resource optimally. Furthermore, because all members of a cooperative group agreed on a common exploitation strategy, we expected inequality among the individual earnings (Gini coefficient of individual earnings) to be very low.
Hypothesis 2
Hypothesis 2 was that cooperative groups would be equally unlikely to cross the potential threshold. This hypothesis hinges on the theoretical prediction that cooperative groups follow the optimal strategy, regardless of treatment. This means that we expected cooperative groups to be equally efficient in their CPR management, regardless of treatment. Apart from this theoretical prediction, testing this hypothesis was of interest because Lindahl et al. (2014) found that cooperative groups react more or less rationally, i.e., optimally, depending on treatment, with cooperative groups facing simple resource dynamics (no threshold) being less efficient than groups facing resource dynamics with certainty about a threshold (threshold treatment, as used in this study).
The predictions we made depended on our assumptions about our subjects. Our hypotheses built on an expected utility framework, whereby subjects were assumed to behave as if they could correctly assign and interpret the probabilities associated with different relevant outcomes and could choose the action that maximized their expected utility based on these probabilities. Moreover, we assumed our subjects were risk-neutral. Assuming that our subjects were risk averse, the quantitative predictions associated with hypothesis 1 might change (see Appendix 6). However, the qualitative predictions, which were what we could and did measure, would not change. As described above, a risk game can be used to explore subjects’ risk preferences.
RESULTS
The results of the risk game reveal that, depending on treatment, 71%-77% of subjects were neither extremely risk averse nor extremely risk seeking. Hence, there was no convincing evidence for changing the prediction of hypothesis 1.
Overall harvest patterns and face-to-face communication
Figure 2 shows time series of resource stock size after group harvest and before growth for each group by treatment (a-d) for the first 14 rounds. The overall harvest patterns in all four treatments were relatively similar: For some rounds or the entire game, some groups underexploited the resource, i.e., resource stock size of >25 units; some achieved a resource stock size of 25-29 units, for which the regeneration rate was highest, in every round of the game; and a few groups moderately overexploited the resource, i.e., resource stock size of 20-24 units.
As Figure 2 also shows, some groups depleted the resource stock: one group in the threshold treatment, four in the high-risk, three in the medium-risk, and six in the low-risk treatment. Of these 14 depletion cases, 8 happened in agreement (see Table 3), a typical reason being that the group thought that the game would end soon (see Table A3.2 in Appendix 3). This result differs from that of other CPR games, in which lack of cooperation is the most usual explanation for resource stock depletion.
Although given the opportunity for face-to-face communication, subjects did not always take advantage of it. In fact, one group did not communicate at all during the whole course of the game, and another four groups did not talk in the first couple of rounds. The main topic of the communication was the common exploitation strategy. Other less frequently discussed topics were when the game might end and whether one could trust the others to act as agreed. From the forms and the experimenter notes, we could deduce that 80% of the groups agreed on a common harvest strategy in the first round; they took the opportunity to communicate and this was effective in that agreement was reached. We call this variable “group agreement round one” (see Table 3 for proportions across treatments). Note that it refers only to agreements made in the first round and that it does not imply that everyone actually followed the agreement. See Appendix 3 for the statistical analysis and all variables used.
Exploitation beyond the potential threshold
Our main variable of interest was whether groups crossed the potential threshold, i.e., severe overexploitation. We found two cases in the threshold treatment group, six cases each in the high- and medium-risk treatment groups, and eight cases in the low-risk treatment group (see Fig. 2). Of the 22 groups, 10 actually played scenario B, and 3 of these 10 groups rebuilt the resource stock to a higher regeneration rate, i.e., reversed the regime shift. To test hypothesis 1 (the higher the probability of a threshold, the fewer cases of severe overexploitation), we used a logistic regression (Maddala 1983) with severe overexploitation as the dependent variable and treatment dummies as predictors. To exclude the possibility of differences between treatments being because of treatment group characteristics other than the probability level of the threshold, we controlled for group size, age, gender, and nationality, i.e., the weird index. The weird index tests the effect of group composition in terms of subjects being from Western, educated, industrialized, rich, democratic (weird) countries (see Henrich et al. 2010; 1 = all subjects are weird). We added this control to our analysis because there is evidence that results of behavioral studies can vary considerable between “nonweird” and “weird” subjects, the latter being the standard subject pool in behavioral studies (Henrich et al. 2010). We classified European, North American, and Australian subjects as weird. Moreover, we controlled for whether groups agreed on a common harvest strategy in the first round. Table 4 shows the results, which indicate that there were no treatment effects, i.e., the number of cases of severe overexploitation did not depend on the probability level. Hence, we could reject hypothesis 1. We also tested whether the introduction of uncertainty, i.e., risk, per se affected whether groups crossed the potential threshold by pooling the risk treatments together and comparing them with the threshold, i.e., certain, treatment. This did not change the results. We found, however, that the likelihood of crossing the potential threshold was negatively related to group agreement in round one. More specifically, the predicted probability of crossing the potential threshold for a group with an agreement in round one (given that all other predictors are set to their mean value) was only 11%.
As Figure 3 shows, there were 9 cooperative groups in the low-risk, 17 in the medium-risk, 9 in the high-risk, and 16 in the threshold treatment (see Table 3 for relative proportions). These cooperative groups (note that they are endogenously determined) achieved an even distribution of earnings by following one or a mix of the following approaches: (1) equal individual harvests in each round or (2) a rotating scheme to keep the total individual earnings equal (see Table A3.2 for group-specific information). As expected, there was no significant difference with respect to the Gini coefficient in individual earnings of the group members. To test hypothesis 2, we compared cases of severe overexploitation among cooperative groups in the four treatments. As Figure 3 shows, in the threshold and high-risk treatments, none of the cooperative groups crossed the potential threshold, in the medium-risk treatment there was one, and in the low-risk treatment two (see Table 3 for proportions). We found that as expected, cooperative groups were equally unlikely to cross the potential threshold (using Fisher’s exact test), independent of treatment. Hence, we were unable to reject hypothesis 2. Please note that when cooperative groups crossed the potential threshold, this happened in agreement, as for cooperative depletion. This, in addition to our theoretical results, provides evidence that cooperation can be seen as a necessary but not sufficient condition for sustainable resource management in our setting.
Evaluating efficiency
On comparing the average efficiency achieved between all four treatments, we found significant differences (Kruskal-Wallis test, p = 0.041), which are only because of a significant difference between the threshold and low-risk treatments (with Bonferroni correction, p = 0.073). Table 3 shows exact values and Figure 4a compares average efficiency achieved over time, including all groups. Considering cooperative groups only, we again found significant differences (Kruskal-Wallis test, p = 0.031). This contradicted our expectations regarding group rationality. Thus, although there were no differences between cooperative groups with respect to crossing the potential threshold, they were not equally efficient in resource management. The significant differences in this case were also because of a significant difference between groups in the threshold and low-risk treatments, the latter being significantly less efficient. In addition, this difference also emerged between the low-risk and high-risk treatments. The average efficiency achieved was higher for cooperative groups in all treatments (Fig. 4b), with the most distinct increase in the high-risk treatment (from 0.720 to 0.874; Table 3). Note that we found no differences between the treatments, considering all groups and only cooperative groups, regarding understanding of resource dynamics in self-reported values from the postexperimental questionnaire (see Table 3).
Figure 3 offers some clues that the higher overall efficiency achieved by the high-risk treatment groups compared with the low-risk groups appears not to have been because of less overexploitation, but to less underexploitation. A Pearson’s chi-square test confirmed this: comparing cases of resource stock size after harvest above 29 resource stock units, cooperative groups in the low-risk treatment underexploited the resource significantly more than cooperative groups in the high-risk treatment (p = 0.000). This indicates that the efficiency measure should be used with care in this case, because it masks some effects by not allowing differentiation between underexploitation and overexploitation. In particular, the latter could lead to a disastrous regime shift, while underexploitation does not. Moreover, for the risk treatments, the efficiency measure also included rounds after the uncertainty resolution; hence, any actions taken by the subjects after this resolution were difficult to interpret. For those reasons, our main variable of interest was whether the groups crossed the potential threshold.
Exploring predictors for avoiding regime shifts
Many previous studies show that cooperation has a positive effect on sustainable resource management, and we are able to confirm this. Figure 5 compares the average resource stock size after harvest for cooperative groups (b) and the remaining noncooperative groups (a). It is clearly apparent that cooperative groups maintained, on average, a resource stock size above the potential threshold, in contrast to noncooperative groups. A Pearson’s chi-square test confirmed that only cooperative groups refrained from crossing the potential threshold (p = 0.000). Moreover, the logistic regression used to test hypothesis 1 indicated that group agreement in round one significantly decreased the likelihood of crossing a potential threshold. Therefore, we explored predictors for initial communication and for cooperation, both of which were endogenously determined. We conducted two logistic regressions, each using a different dependent variable: group agreement round one, model (1) in Table 5; and cooperative group, model (2) in Table 5. In addition to treatment dummies, we included a dummy for group size and variables to control for age, gender, and nationality (weird index) in the groups. We also controlled for whether subjects knew each other before the experiment, because this could have influenced initiating communication and cooperation in particular, because of the specific communication design. As model (1b) in Table 5 shows, the odds of group agreement in round one are positively related to the threshold and high-risk treatment and to groups with a higher proportion of females. These results suggest that the threshold and high-risk treatments and gender composition were not good controls for the first regression we used, in which crossing the potential threshold was the dependent variable. See the Results section on exploitation beyond the potential threshold. We ran a two-stage logistic regression in which we used the predicted values from the model (1) regression in the first regression (crossing potential threshold). We found that group agreement in round one was still significant, suggesting that the threshold and high-risk treatments, as well as gender composition, had an indirect effect on whether or not groups crossed the potential threshold. As Model (2b) in Table 5 shows, the odds for cooperative groups were positively related to the threshold and medium-risk treatments.
DISCUSSION
Abundant empirical evidence (e.g., Tversky and Kahneman 1974) suggests that in complex and uncertain decision problems, as in our experiment, the assumptions that underlie expected utility theory are highly questionable. In such situations, decision makers typically violate the principles of expected utility maximization and rely instead on shortcuts or heuristics, which are sometimes systematically biased (Tversky and Kahneman 1974). Empirical cognitive research suggests that people generally have problems with interpreting probabilities. For example, people tend to systematically overweight small probabilities and underweight large and moderate probabilities (Kahneman and Tversky 1979, Tversky and Kahneman 1992). Such a bias can explain why we observed no distinct difference between the low-risk and high-risk treatments regarding severe overexploitation, in contrast to our theoretical predictions and the number of cooperative groups. Another potential explanation could, of course, be our particular face-to-face communication design. We allowed communication at all stages of the game, and subjects were seated around a table and could look into each other’s faces. We found that once a group made a decision on a common harvest strategy and followed it for a few rounds, individuals would not break this group agreement easily. Hence, we should perhaps not be surprised to find no distinctive difference between the high-risk and low-risk treatments regarding severe overexploitation and cooperative groups. This design feature might also explain the large number of cooperative groups we found in general, across all four treatments.
However, our particular face-to-face communication design cannot explain why the medium-risk treatment (0.5) outperformed the high-risk treatment (0.9) with more cooperative groups. Another common bias could explain why the medium-risk treatment stood out: people tend to judge probabilities by the ease of association to relevant examples. This is referred to as “availability” (Tversky and Kahneman 1973) and may explain why disproportionately high weight is assigned to more easily remembered information. Recall that in the medium-risk treatment, the probability of a threshold was described as flipping a coin, a procedure with which most people are familiar, can relate to, and can use as a reference when assigning a probability weight. A 50/50 chance of a threshold can then be viewed as very likely. In comparison, a probability of 0.9 (or 0.1) is much harder to relate to and to assign an accurate probability weight to.
We found no differences between the high-risk and low-risk treatments regarding the number of cooperative groups. However, there were differences in efficiency; i.e., group rationality did not hold. This was not because the low-risk treatment induced more overexploitation, although that would be expected because deviations from the optimal strategy in the direction of overharvesting were more costly in the high-risk treatment. Instead, cooperative groups in the high-risk treatment underexploited the resource significantly less than groups in the low-risk treatment. They anchored their decisions on the very likely threshold; i.e., they coordinated around the strategy of not crossing the potential threshold, making them more efficient. This (perhaps counterintuitive) result also indicates that efficiency might not be a good measurement for resource management when the possibility of an endogenously driven disastrous regime shift exists. Our results indicate that under certain conditions, i.e., cooperation and high risk, a threshold can serve as a focal point that helps people coordinate and thereby protect ecological functions they depend on. This suggests that it may be fruitful to further study how to exploit people’s tendency to simplify complex problems and coordinate around a solution that seems easy to achieve (see Schelling 1960 on focal points). If the threshold is not known, a potential policy intervention could be to use safe minimum standards (Ciriacy-Wantrup 1952) as a signaling device.
Several experimental studies (e.g., Messick et al. 1988, Budescu et al. 1990) have shown that introducing environmental uncertainty in commons dilemmas leads to more cases of overexploitation. Our results contradict this finding. Those studies on environmental uncertainty and the studies that introduced endogenously driven resource dynamics (e.g., Prediger et al. 2011, Cardenas et al. 2013) did not permit communication. Previous CPR research shows that face-to-face communication per se is important for determining whether groups will cooperate or not (e.g., Pretty 2003, Ostrom 2006). There is also considerable empirical evidence in the experimental literature of the positive effect of communication on cooperation (e.g., Sally 1995 and Balliet 2009 for literature reviews). Lindahl et al. (2014) showed that the effectiveness of communication (making group agreements), which underlies cooperation, can be endogenous to the decision problem. We can support this finding, because there were differences across the four treatments in making group agreements in the first round and in cooperation, for which effective communication is a necessary condition. Lindahl et al. (2014) could not identify the triggers of effective communication, whether it is the latent regime shift that people perceive as a threat or the complex decision problem. Our results support the threat hypothesis. Indeed, although the level of complexity was similar in all risk treatments, we found that significantly more groups in the threshold and high-risk treatments than in the medium- and low-risk treatments made an agreement in the first round; in the latter two, the risk, i.e., the threat of a latent regime shift, was lower. A potential regime shift is clearly associated with potential welfare losses and can be seen as a threat.
We focused solely on risk situations; i.e., all the possible outcomes and their probability distribution are known. This setting could describe real situations for well-studied ecosystems in which the probability of a regime shift occurring in the future can be roughly extrapolated from past behavior in similar systems. However, many real-life situations are not so clear. For example, one can usually only predict a range where the system might shift (Biggs et al. 2012), and often one cannot determine whether a system has possible alternate regimes and what these might be. Coral reefs, which are relatively well studied in this respect, can even have more than two different regimes (Norström et al. 2009). This profound lack of information about ecosystems calls for further studies on behavior regarding different aspects of environmental uncertainty. A natural extension of this study would be to test the impacts of uncertain threshold location. An experimental study by Barrett and Dannenberg (2012) on a threshold public-good game showed that uncertainty about the location of the threshold, when huge welfare losses were at stake, significantly decreased contribution levels. However, they used a one-shot game. Future research could also study people’s behavior toward surprise, e.g., an unexpected drop in resource renewal rate, uncertainty about the size of the hysteresis, or other ecological features. For policy purposes, it might be relevant to explore whether, and how, the nonstandard motivations (biases) mentioned above play out in our experimental design. For example, we could extend the design to test the effect of how probabilities are presented to the subjects by using a 10-sided dice instead of a draw to determine the low- and high-risk treatment scenarios. We believe that rolling a dice is easier to understand and could therefore diminish the availability bias, which we hypothesized could be a potential cause of our counterintuitive results; e.g., medium risk produced more cooperation than high risk.
We want to highlight that our results stem from laboratory experiments with students as subjects and as such we should be cautious when we generalize the findings. One criticism relates to the fact that the typical subjects of laboratory experiments represent only a very restricted sample of humanity; i.e., they can be called “weird” (see the Results section and Henrich et al. 2010). However, our subject pool was relatively diverse; about a third of our subjects came from a “nonweird” country. We did not find, however, that the weird index had an effect and that might be because a “nonweird” student coming to Sweden to study may in fact have a background similar to that of a “weird” student, which may render our control unsatisfactory. To increase confidence in our results, a natural next step would be to take this design to the field. As Harrison and List (2004) point out, to extrapolate experimental findings beyond the laboratory, it is necessary to perform several types of experiments.
CONCLUSIONS
In this experimental study, we explored how groups deal with different probability levels regarding a latent endogenously driven ecosystem regime shift that negatively and persistently affects the availability of a commonly shared resource. We found that whether or not people face such a latent shift with certainty or different risk levels (low, medium, high) does not make them more or less likely to exploit the resource beyond its critical potential threshold. However, if the likelihood of the latent shift was certain or high and if there were more females in the group, groups were more prone to initially agree on a common exploitation strategy, which in turn increased the likelihood of averting the latent shift. Furthermore, we found that cooperative groups are equally unlikely to cross the potential threshold. The risk level also influenced how efficient the groups were in managing the resource and whether or not groups cooperated. Cooperative groups facing a threshold with certainty or a 90% chance performed better, generating higher payoffs and managing the resource more sustainably. Threshold certainty and a 50/50 chance of being confronted with a threshold also increased the likelihood of cooperation. We attributed this outcome, i.e., medium risk produced more cooperation than high risk, to possible different behavioral responses to the two ways used to present the probabilities in the game, i.e., lottery versus flipping a coin. Hence, risk influenced individual and group behavior in our CPR setting and triggered certain behaviors, but the exact levels of risk that triggered a particular behavioral response (group agreement in round one and cooperation) were ambiguous and need further exploration.
Based on the results, some recommendations can be made on how to support decision making for vulnerable populations whose actions could trigger ecosystem regime shifts that negatively affect the basis for their livelihoods. First, the potential for such undesirable regime shifts should be communicated, especially in situations when the actual risk is high or certain, because we found that such situations increase the likelihood of user groups engaging early in decision making on how to manage the CPR, which in turn is a predictor for averting an undesirable regime shift. Second, long-term collective action should be promoted, because it is likely to prevent latent regime shifts and also enables more sustainable resource management in social-ecological terms. Finally, rather than assessing accurate risk levels, clear thought is needed about how to communicate risks. We found that people may have difficulties in grasping probabilities other than a 50/50 chance, which they can easily visualize, e.g., flipping a coin. In a nutshell, the risk level, how it is communicated, and collective action play a role in preventing human activities like resource extraction from pushing an ecosystem into an undesirable state.
RESPONSES TO THIS ARTICLE
Responses to this article are invited. If accepted for publication, your response will be hyperlinked to the article. To submit a response, follow this link. To read responses already accepted, follow this link.ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
We are thankful for financial support from the EU FP7 Arctic Tipping Point (ATP) project (contract #226248), the EU FP7 ACCESS project contract #265863) under the call Ocean of Tomorrow, FORMAS SUPER-project (# 250-2010-145), the Ebba and Sven Schwartz Foundation, the Stockholm Resilience Centre, and the Kjell and Märta Beijer Foundation. We gratefully acknowledge comments received from three anonymous reviewers, the guest editor of this special feature, and seminar participants at the following conferences, workshops, and seminars: CSID workshop, University of Arizona, Tempe, Arizona, USA (March 2013); 20th EAERE conference, Toulouse, France (June 2013); 20th Ulvön conference, Ulvön, Sweden (June 2013); seminar at the Department of Economics, Umeå University, Umeå, Sweden (October 2013); and WOW5, Indiana University, Bloomington, Indiana, USA (June 2014). We thank Johanna Drie, Nikolina Oreskovic, and Britt Stikvoort for experiment assistance and Daniel Ospina-Medina, Matías Piaggio, and Chandra Kiran for valuable discussions. Last but not least, we would like to thank our experiment participants. Part of this study was initiated as the first author’s Master's thesis (Schill 2012).
LITERATURE CITED
Anderies, J. M., M. A. Janssen, F. Bousquet, J.-C. Cardenas, D. Castillo, M.-C. Lopez, R. Tobias, B. Vollan, and A. Wutich. 2011. The challenge of understanding decisions in experimental studies of common pool resource governance. Ecological Economics 70:1571-1579. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2011.01.011
Balliet, D. 2009. Communication and cooperation in social dilemmas: a meta-analytic review. Journal of Conflict Resolution 54:39-57. http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/0022002709352443
Barrett, S., and A. Dannenberg. 2012. Climate negotiations under scientific uncertainty. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 109:17372-17376. http://dx.doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1208417109
Berkes, F., and C. Folke. 1998. Linking social and ecological systems: management practices and social mechanisms for building resilience. Cambridge Univeristy Press, Cambridge, UK.
Biggs, R., T. Blenckner, C. Folke, L. Gordon, A. Norström, M. Nyström, and G. D. Peterson. 2012. Regime shifts. Pages 1-19 in A. Hastings and L. Gross, editors. Sourcebook in theoretical ecology. University of California Press, Berkeley, California, USA.
Biggs, R., S. R. Carpenter, and W. A. Brock. 2009. Turning back from the brink: detecting an impending regime shift in time to avert it. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 106:826-831. http://dx.doi.org/10.1073/pnas.0811729106
Brock, W. A., and S. R. Carpenter. 2012. Early warnings of regime shift when the ecosystem structure is unknown. PLoS ONE 7(9):e45586. http://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0045586
Brock, W. A., and D. Starrett. 2003. Managing systems with non-convex positive feedback. Environmental and Resource Economics 26:575-602. http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/B:EARE.0000007350.11040.e3
Budescu, D. V., A. Rapoport, and R. Suleiman. 1990. Resource dilemmas with environmental uncertainty and asymetric players. European Journal of Social Psychology 20:475-487. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/ejsp.2420200603
Cárdenas, J. C. 2009. Experiments in environment and development. Annual Review of Resource Economics 1:157-182. http://dx.doi.org/10.1146/annurev.resource.050708.144056
Cardenas, J.-C., M. A. Janssen, and F. Bousquet. 2013. Dynamics of rules and resources: three new field experiments on water, forests and fisheries. Pages 319-345 in J. A. List and M. K. Price, editors. Handbook on experimental economics and the environment. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK. http://dx.doi.org/10.4337/9781781009079.00020
Castillo, D., F. Bousquet, M. A. Janssen, K. Worrapimphong, and J. C. Cardenas. 2011. Context matters to explain field experiments: results from Colombian and Thai fishing villages. Ecological Economics 70:1609-1620. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2011.05.011
Ciriacy-Wantrup, S. V. 1952. Resource conservation. University of California Press, Berkeley, California, USA.
Crépin, A.-S. 2003. Multiple species boreal forests—what Faustmann missed. Environmental and Resource Economics 26:625-646. http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/B:EARE.0000007352.02799.0e
Crépin, A.-S. 2007. Using fast and slow processes to manage resources with thresholds. Environmental and Resource Economics 36:191-213. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10640-006-9029-8
Crépin, A.-S., R. Biggs, S. Polasky, M. Troell, and A. de Zeeuw. 2012. Regime shifts and management. Ecological Economics 84:15-22. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2012.09.003
Crépin, A.-S., and T. Lindahl. 2009. Grazing games: sharing common property resources with complex dynamics. Environmental and Resource Economics 44:29-46. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10640-008-9258-0
Folke, C., S. Carpenter, B. Walker, M. Scheffer, T. Elmqvist, L. Gunderson, and C. S. Holling. 2004. Regime shifts, resilience, and biodiversity in ecosystem management. Annual Review of Ecology, Evolution, and Systematics 35:557-581. http://dx.doi.org/10.1146/annurev.ecolsys.35.021103.105711
Gordon, L. J., G. D. Peterson, and E. M. Bennett. 2008. Agricultural modifications of hydrological flows create ecological surprises. Trends in Ecology and Evolution 23:211-219. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.tree.2007.11.011
Gustafsson, M., A. Biel, and T. Gärling. 1999. Overharvesting of resources of unknown size. Acta Psychologica 103:47-64. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0001-6918(99)00024-4
Harrison, G. W., and J. A. List. 2004. Field experiments. Journal of Economic Literature 42:1009-1055. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/0022051043004577
Hastings, A., and D. B. Wysham. 2010. Regime shifts in ecological systems can occur with no warning. Ecology Letters 13:464-472. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1461-0248.2010.01439.x
Henrich, J., S. J. Heine, and A. Norenzayan. 2010. The weirdest people in the world? Behavioral and Brain Sciences 33:61-83. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0140525X0999152X
Hine, D. W., and R. Gifford. 1996. Individual restraint and group efficiency in commons dilemmas: the effects of two types of environmental uncertainty. Journal of Applied Social Psychology 26:993-1009. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1559-1816.1996.tb01121.x
Holling, C. S. 1987. Simplifying the complex: the paradigms of ecological function and structure. European Journal of Operational Research 30:139-146. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0377-2217(87)90091-9
Janssen, M. A. 2010. Introducing ecological dynamics into common-pool resource experiments. Ecology and Society 15(2): 7. [online] URL: http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol15/iss2/art7/
Janssen, M. A., R. Holahan, A. Lee, and E. Ostrom. 2010. Lab experiments for the study of social-ecological systems. Science 328:613-617. http://dx.doi.org/10.1126/science.1183532
Janssen, M. A., A. Lee, and T. M. Waring. 2014. Experimental platforms for behavioral experiments on social-ecological systems. Ecology and Society 19(4): 20. http://dx.doi.org/10.5751/ES-06895-190420
Kahneman, D., and A. Tversky. 1979. Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47:263-292. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1914185
Kimbrough, E. O., and A. Vostroknutov. 2013. The social and ecological determinants of common pool resource sustainability. Working paper. Indiana University, Bloomington, Indiana, USA. [online] URL: http://hdl.handle.net/10535/9106
Lade, S. J., and T. Gross. 2012. Early warning signals for critical transitions: a generalized modeling approach. PLoS Computational Biology 8(2):e1002360. http://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pcbi.1002360
Levin, S. A. 1998. Ecosystems and the biosphere as complex adaptive systems. Ecosystems 1:431-436. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s100219900037
Levin, S., T. Xepapadeas, A.-S. Crépin, J. Norberg, A. de Zeeuw, C. Folke, T. Hughes, K. Arrow, S. Barrett, G. Daily, P. Ehrlich, N. Kautsky, K.-G. Mäler, S. Polasky, M. Troell, J. R. Vincent, and B. Walker. 2013. Social-ecological systems as complex adaptive systems: modeling and policy implications. Environment and Development Economics 18:111-132. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S1355770X12000460
Likert, R. 1932. A technique for the measurement of attitudes. Archives of Psychology 140:1-55.
Lindahl, T., A.-S. Crépin, and C. Schill. 2012. Managing resources with potential regime shifts: using experiments to explore social-ecological linkages in common resource system. Beijer Discussion Paper Series 232. Beijer Institute of Ecological Economics, Stockholm, Sweden.
Lindahl, T., A.-S. Crépin, and C. Schill. 2014. Potential disasters can turn the tragedy into success. Beijer Discussion Paper Series 244. Beijer Institute of Ecological Economics, Stockholm, Sweden.
Maddala, G. S. 1983. Limited-dependent and qualitative variables in econometrics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts, USA. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511810176
Mäler, K.-G., A. Xepapadeas, and A. de Zeeuw. 2003. The economics of shallow lakes. Environmental and Resource Economics 26:603-624. http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/B:EARE.0000007351.99227.42
Messick, D. M., S. T. Allison, and C. D. Samuelson. 1988. Framing and communication effects on group members responses to environmental and social uncertainty. Pages 677-700 in S. Maital, editor. Applied behavioral economics. New York University Press, New York, New York, USA.
Millennium Ecosystem Assessment. 2005. Ecosystems and human well-being: synthesis. Island Press, Washington, D.C., USA.
Moreno-Sánchez, R. P., and J. H. Maldonado. 2010. Evaluating the role of co-management in improving governance of marine protected areas: an experimental approach in the Colombian Caribbean. Ecological Economics 69:2557-2567. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2010.07.032
Norström, A. V., M. Nyström, J. Lokrantz, and C. Folke. 2009. Alternative states on coral reefs: beyond coral-macroalgal phase shifts. Marine Ecology Progress Series 376:295-306. http://dx.doi.org/10.3354/meps07815
Osés-Eraso, N., F. Udina, and M. Viladrich-Grau. 2008. Environmental versus human-induced scarcity in the commons: do they trigger the same response? Environmental and Resource Economics 40:529-550. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10640-007-9168-6
Ostrom, E. 1990. Governing the commons: the evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge University Press, New York, New York, USA. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511807763
Ostrom, E. 2006. The value-added of laboratory experiments for the study of institutions and common-pool resources. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 61:149-163. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2005.02.008
Ostrom, E. 2009. A general framework for analyzing sustainability of social-ecological systems. Science 325:419-422. http://dx.doi.org/10.1126/science.1172133
Ostrom, E., R. Gardner, and J. Walker. 1994. Rules, games, and common-pool resources. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor, Michigan, USA.
Polasky, S., A. de Zeeuw, and F. Wagener. 2011. Optimal management with potential regime shifts. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 62:229-240. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2010.09.004
Poteete, A. R., M. A. Janssen, and E. Ostrom. 2010. Working together: collective action, the commons, and multiple methods in practice. Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey, USA. http://dx.doi.org/10.1515/9781400835157
Prediger, S., B. Vollan, and M. Frölich. 2011. The impact of culture and ecology on cooperation in a common-pool resource experiment. Ecological Economics 70:1599-1608. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2010.08.017
Pretty, J. 2003. Social capital and the collective management of resources. Science 302:1912-1914. http://dx.doi.org/10.1126/science.1090847
Rapoport, A., D. V. Budescu, R. Suleiman, and E. Weg. 1992. Social dilemmas with uniformly distributed resources. Pages 43-57 in W. B. G. Liebrand, D. M. Messick, and H. A. M. Wilke, editors. Social dilemmas: theoretical issues and research findings. Pergamon, Oxford, UK.
Rocha, J., J. Yletyinen, R. Biggs, T. Blenckner, and G. Peterson. 2015. Marine regime shifts: drivers and impacts on ecosystems services. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B 370(1659): 20130273. http://dx.doi.org/10.1098/rstb.2013.0273
Rockström, J., W. Steffen, K. Noone, Å. Persson, F. S. Chapin, III, E. Lambin, T. M. Lenton, M. Scheffer, C. Folke, H. J. Schellnhuber, B. Nykvist, C. A. De Wit, T. Hughes, S. Van der Leeuw, H. Rodhe, S. Sörlin, P. K. Snyder, R. Costanza, U. Svedin, M. Falkenmark, L. Karlberg, R. W. Corell, V. J. Fabry, J. Hansen, B. Walker, D. Liverman, K. Richardson, P. Crutzen, and J. Foley. 2009. Planetary boundaries: exploring the safe operating space for humanity. Ecology and Society 14(2): 32. [online] URL: http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol14/iss2/art32/
Sally, D. 1995. Conversation and cooperation in social dilemmas: a meta-analysis of experiments from 1958 to 1992. Rationality and Society 7:58-92. http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/1043463195007001004
Scheffer, M., S. Carpenter, J. A. Foley, C. Folke, and B. Walker. 2001. Catastrophic shifts in ecosystems. Nature 413:591-596. http://dx.doi.org/10.1038/35098000
Scheffer, M., S. R. Carpenter, T. M. Lenton, J. Bascompte, W. Brock, V. Dakos, J. van de Koppel, I. A. van de Leemput, S. A. Levin, E. H. van Nes, M. Pascual, and J. Vandermeer. 2012. Anticipating critical transitions. Science 338:344-348. http://dx.doi.org/10.1126/science.1225244
Schelling, T. C. 1960. The strategy of conflict. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts, USA.
Schill, C. 2012. Identifying factors influencing exploitation strategies and cooperation in commons dilemmas under threshold uncertainty: evidence from a laboratory experiment. Thesis. Stockholm University, Stockholm, Sweden.
Steffen, W., R. A. Sanderson, P. D. Tyson, J. Jäger, P. A. Matson, B. Moore, III, F. Oldfield, K. Richardson, H.-J. Schellnhuber, B. L. Turner, II, and R. J. Wasson. 2004. Global change and the earth system: a planet under pressure. Springer, Heidelberg, Germany.
Stern, N. 2007. The economics of climate change: the Stern review. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511817434
Sturm, B., and J. Weimann. 2006. Experiment in environmental economics and some close relatives. Journal of Economic Surveys 20:419-458. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.0950-0804.2006.00285.x
Turner, B. L., II, R. E. Kasperson, P. A. Matson, J. J. McCarthy, R. W. Corell, L. Christensen, N. Eckley, J. X. Kasperson, A. Luers, M. L. Martello, C. Polsky, A. Pulsipher, and A. Schiller. 2003. A framework for vulnerability analysis in sustainability science. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 100:8074-8079. http://dx.doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1231335100
Tversky, A., and D. Kahneman. 1973. Availability: a heuristic for judging frequency and probability. Cognitive Psychology 5:207-232. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0010-0285(73)90033-9
Tversky, A., and D. Kahneman. 1974. Judgment under uncertainty: heuristics and biases. Science 185:1124-1131. http://dx.doi.org/10.1126/science.185.4157.1124
Tversky, A., and D. Kahneman. 1992. Advances in prospect theory: cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 5:297-323. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/BF00122574
Walker, J. M., and R. Gardner. 1992. Probabilistic destruction of common-pool resources: experimental evidence. Economic Journal 102:1149-1161. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2234382
Wilson, J. 2002. Scientific uncertainty, complex systems, and the design of common-pool institutions. Pages 327-359 in E. Ostrom, T. Dietz, N. Dolšak, P. C. Stern, S. Stonich, and E. U. Weber, editors. Drama of the commons. National Academy Press, Washington, D.C., USA.
Table 1
Table 1. Experimental design.
Treatment 1: Threshold† |
Treatment 2: High risk of threshold |
Treatment 3: Medium risk of threshold‡ |
Treatment 4: Low risk of threshold |
|
Probability of threshold |
1.0 | 0.9 | 0.5 | 0.1 |
Description | Subjects knew that there was a threshold. | Subjects were presented with two different resource dynamics scenarios, a logistic type (A) and one that entailed a threshold (B). They knew the probability of either being played. | ||
Number of groups§ | 20 [7/13] | 21 [7/14] | 23 [5/18] | 20 [10/10] |
Number of subjects | 73 | 77 | 87 | 70 |
†This treatment is identical with the threshold treatment in Lindahl et al. (2012, 2014). ‡This treatment is identical to the threshold uncertainty treatment in Schill (2012). §Numbers in squared brackets indicate number of groups with three/four subjects. |
Table 2
Table 2. Subject pool characteristics.
Threshold treatment | High-risk treatment | Medium-risk treatment | Low-risk treatment | |
Average group age | 28.39 (1.70) | 25.16 (0.49) | 25.66 (0.41) | 25.85 (0.79) |
Average group gender composition† | 0.63 (0.07) | 0.35 (0.06) | 0.39 (0.05) | 0.5 (0.06) |
Average individual earnings in SEK (group level)‡ | 180.58 (9.92) | 176.63 (8.23) | 167.68 (8.18) | 177.00 (8.61) |
Nationalities§ | 65.5% European (26% Swedish), 26.9% Asians, 5.5% North Americans, 1.7% Africans, 0.3% Australians | |||
Weird group index† | 0.71 (0.40) | 0.80 (0.21) | 0.61 (0.27) | 0.73 (0.29) |
Note: Standard error in brackets. †These variables are dichotomous on individual level (female = 1; subjects from a Western, educated, industrialized, rich, democratic [weird] country = 1 [see Henrich et al. 2010], European, North American, and Australian subjects = weird). ‡SEK 1.00 corresponds to EUR 0.11/ USD 0.15. Average earnings plus show-up fee (≈ EUR 36/USD 49) provide students on Stockholm University campus with lunch for about a week. Given the relatively low income of our subjects, the cost of suboptimal decision making was quite high for most of them. Hence, the fact that the part of the reward that is not tied to actual decisions (show-up fee) is relatively large is likely to have had no substantial influence on the results. §N = 290. We had instructions available in both Swedish and English. As soon as there was one subject in the group that did not speak Swedish, the experimenter only permitted communication in English. |
Table 3
Table 3. Comparison of proportions and averages across the four treatments for all groups and cooperative groups only.
Threshold treatment | High-risk treatment | Medium-risk treatment | Low-risk treatment | p (Kruskal-Wallis test or χ²/Fisher’s exact test)† |
|
All groups |
|||||
N |
20 |
21 |
23 |
20 |
-- |
Proportion of crossing potential threshold cases‡ | 0.10 | 0.29 | 0.26 | 0.40 | 0.192 |
Proportion of modest overexploitation cases |
0.15 | 0.29 | 0.09 | 0.25 | 0.329 |
Proportion of depletion cases |
0.05 [0] | 0.19 [0.25] | 0.13 [0.67] | 0.30 [0.83] | 0.196 |
Proportion of groups with agreement in round one | 0.95 | 0.86 | 0.78 | 0.60 | 0.052 |
Average Gini coefficient (individual earnings) |
0.025 (0.064) | 0.062 (0.098) | 0.036 (0.070) | 0.050 (0.084) | 0.141 |
Average efficiency | 0.835 (0.160) | 0.720 (0.241) | 0.752 (0.191) | 0.667 (0.228) | 0.041 |
Average understanding of resource dynamics§ |
4.513 (0.457) | 4.389 (0.547) | 4.265 (0.642) | 4.388 (0.361) | 0.517 |
Cooperative groups | |||||
N |
16 |
9 |
17 |
9 |
-- |
Proportion of cooperative groups |
0.80 | 0.43 | 0.74 | 0.45 | 0.022 |
Proportion of crossing potential threshold cases | 0.00 | 0.00 | 0.06 | 0.22 | 0.180 |
Proportion of modest overexploitation cases |
0.19 | 0.33 | 0.06 | 0.22 | 0.323 |
Proportion of cooperative depletion cases |
0.00 | 0.11 | 0.06 | 0.33 | 0.051 |
Average Gini coefficient (individual earnings) |
0.003 (0.003) | 0.007 (0.015) | 0.004 (0.004) | 0.007 (0.015) | 0.888 |
Average efficiency | 0.857 (0.158) | 0.874 (0.075) | 0.804 (0.129) | 0.705 (0.155) | 0.033 |
Average understanding of resource dynamics§ |
4.578 (0.397) | 4.537 (0.334) | 4.368 (0.458) | 4.602 (0.291) | 0.464 |
Note: Standard error in brackets. Proportion of cooperative depletion cases in square brackets. See Table A3.1 in Appendix 3 for a description of the variables used. †Kruskal-Wallis test used to compare averages across treatments and χ²/Fisher’s exact test used to compare proportions across treatments (see Appendix 3 for information on statistical analysis). ‡Across the four treatments, the proportions account for 22 groups, of which 11 depleted the resource stock soon after having crossed the potential threshold (see Table A3.2 in Appendix 3 for reasons for depletion for each group). §Self-reported variable, obtained from postexperimental questionnaire (see Appendix 2). |
Table 4
Table 4. Logistic regression results on crossing the potential threshold.
Variable | Crossing potential threshold | |
Coef. | (Std. err.) | |
Constant | 0.043 | (2.725) |
High-risk treatment | 1.456 | (1.159) |
Medium-risk treatment | 1.173 | (1.092) |
Low-risk treatment | 0.721 | (1.069) |
Group agreement round one | -3.340*** | (0.841) |
Group of 4 subjects | -1.008 | (0.662) |
Average age | -0.011 | (0.086) |
Gender composition† | 1.429 | (1.306) |
Weird index† | 0.922 | (1.286) |
LR χ² | 31.27*** | |
Pseudo R² | 0.324 | |
N | 84 | |
Note: The dependent variable crossing potential threshold (severe overexploitation) is a binary variable (value 1 denotes that group crossed the potential threshold). See Table A3.1 in Appendix 3 for a description of the variables used. †These variables are dichotomous on individual level (female = 1; weird = 1). ***p < 0.01; **p < 0.05; *p < 0.1. |
Table 5
Table 5. Logistic regression results of group agreement in round one and cooperative group.
Variable | Model (1a) - Group agreement round one |
Model (1b) - Group agreement round one |
Model (2a) - Cooperative group |
Model (2b) - Cooperative group |
Coef. (std. err.) | Coef. (std. err.) | Coef. (std. err.) | Coef. (std. err.) | |
Constant | -0.601 (2.227) | -0.975 (0.775) | -1.044 (1.859) | -1.103 (1.746) |
High-risk treatment | 1.512* (0.872) | 1.688** (0.851) | -0.078 (0.672) | -0.101 (0.641) |
Medium-risk treatment | 0.984 (0.767) | 0.908 (0.748) | 1.151* (0.681) | 1.164* (0.671) |
Threshold treatment | 2.665** (1.275) | 2.357** (1.152) | 1.357* (0.757) | 1.369* (0.743) |
Know others from before | 0.581 (1.094) | 0.783 (0.785) | 0.798 (0.784) | |
Group of 4 subjects | 0.916 (0.626) | 0.858 (0.614) | 0.174 (0.513) | 0.185 (0.509) |
Average age | -0.045 (0.079) | 0.028 (0.065) | 0.025 (0.063) | |
Gender composition† | 1.640 (1.222) | 1.997* (1.178) | 0.034 (0.961) | |
Weird index† | 1.121 (1.197) | -0.189 (0.915) | ||
LR χ² | 15.10* | 13.93** | 11.35 | 11.31* |
Pseudo R² | 0.178 | 0.165 | 0.101 | 0.1005 |
N | 84 | 84 | 84 | 84 |
Note: The dependent variables group agreement round one and cooperative group are binary variables (value 1 denotes that a group made an agreement in round one or was classified as a cooperative group). According to a likelihood ratio test, the reduced models (1b) and (2b) lead to significantly better fit (test results for Model (1): LR χ² = 1.17, p=0.76; Model (2): LR χ² = 0.04, p=0.98). See Table A3.1 in Appendix 3 for a description of the variables used. Other model specifications are available upon request. †These variables are dichotomous on individual level (female = 1; weird = 1). ***p < 0.01; **p < 0.05; *p < 0.1 |